I Am His
The pursuit of happiness is on! Not Jefferson’s version, the one he
slipped into the Declaration of Independence in place of property. I
mean the stampede to study happiness, create happiness measures for
national policy, and publish pop-science and how-to books on the
subject.
Bhutan’s Gross National Happiness Commission uses
citizens’ reports of their happiness to assess national progress, and
former French President Nicholas Sarkozy appointed a Nobel-encrusted
commission to study a similar idea; the United Nations places “happiness
indicators” on its war-burdened agenda; American science institutions
pour money into fine-tuning measurements of “subjective well-being”; and
Amazon’s list of happiness books by moonlighting professors runs from The Happiness Hypothesis to Stumbling on Happiness, Authentic Happiness, Engineering Happiness, and beyond.
Since
at least the 1950s, academics have analyzed surveys asking people how
happy or satisfied they feel. We’ve used fuzzy questions such as, “Taken
all together, how would you say things are these days—would you say
that you are very happy, pretty happy, or not too happy?” to assess
respondents’ morale. We’ve compared, say, women to men and the poor to
the rich. Dutch sociologist Ruut Veenhoven started compiling the
findings into his World Database of Happiness back in the 1980s.
So what set off the current frenzy? Economists found happiness.
In
the decade after 2000, the number of articles on happiness in major
economics journals roughly tripled. One economist told me a couple of
years ago that his colleagues’ pursuit of happiness was depressing him.
Nonetheless, established leaders and bright new scholars turned to the
topic and brought with them the funding, media prestige, and political
clout of the profession. That a guild which prides itself on scientific
rigor and hardheadedness would embrace such a sappy concept measured in
such mushy ways is, well, bemusing. Even Federal Reserve Chief Ben
Bernanke drew on the new economics of happiness to find the moral for
his 2010 commencement address to University of South Carolina graduates:
“I urge you to take this research to heart by making time for friends
and family and by being part of and contributing to a larger community.”
The
embrace resulted, I think, from the great challenge the emergence of
behavioral economics posed to the discipline. Standard economics assumes
that people are rational deciders, and they reveal their preferences,
what gives them “utility,” by their choices. But, as I discussed in the last issue of Boston Review,
people often have confused preferences, make sub-optimal selections,
and regret their decisions. Because of this, Nobel Prize–winner Daniel
Kahneman and current Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers Alan
Krueger wrote in 2006, “An exclusive reliance on choices to infer what
people desire loses some of its appeal.”
If economics is all
about individuals optimizing their utility, but that utility is not
revealed by people’s actual choices, how then do we know which economic
behaviors and policies are optimal? Track happiness. Kahneman and
Kreuger have mounted projects to do just that, trying to bring the
measurement precision of, say, steel production reports and the Fed’s
overnight interest rate, to happiness. Study subjects are asked to list
their activities of the previous day and rate the pleasure and pain they
felt then. (This is cheaper than “experience sampling,” in which
subjects report their moment-by-moment feelings via a pager or similar
device.) The returns from this research investment have so far been
slight.
• • •
What do we know about happiness? We know that people’s reports of immediate joy and misery fluctuate from activity to activity—sex is an upper; commuting is a downer—and often diverge notably from the summary answers they give to questions about their happiness “these days.” We also know that subjective well-being can be complex. People can be happy about work and sad about love; the latter usually matters more. The opposite of happiness, research suggests, is not necessarily despair, but rather apathy; some people just don’t feel much of anything.
Nonetheless,
people who say they are generally happy tend to be economically secure,
married, healthy, religious, and busy with friends; they tend to live
in affluent, democratic, individualistic societies with activist,
welfare-state governments. The connection between reporting happiness
and personal traits often runs both ways. For example, being healthy
adds to happiness, and happy people also stay healthier.
For
decades, researchers have been especially interested in—and, with the
recent invasion of economists, are now obsessed with—whether money makes
people happy. We know that being poor makes people less happy. Some
researchers argue, however, that having more money beyond that needed
for basic security returns no additional happiness and can even create
unhappiness. Making more money may be fruitless because people adapt
psychologically to their levels of wealth and, like addicts and drugs,
need ever more money to get the same level of pleasure. Or perhaps it’s
not really about the money; it’s about position. People chase money to
feel superior to the folks next door. That, of course, becomes a vicious
and pointless cycle. Other researchers, including Veenhoven, agree that
the more money one makes, the more money it takes to move the happiness
meter, but they nevertheless insist that more money—unlike the futile
experience with drugs—does bring more happiness, just at a slower pace among the well-to-do. The data appear to support that position.
The
money-happiness question was initially raised by economist Richard
Easterlin, who observed that growing affluence since the mid-twentieth
century had not led to more reports of happiness in national surveys.
(Actually, Freud raised a similar question in Civilization and Its Discontents,
in 1929.) One explanation of the Easterlin Paradox, aside from
adaptation and competition, is that increasing materialism ruined the
pleasure Americans might have gotten from becoming wealthier. Some,
including your correspondent, have argued that there is no paradox to
start with, because the growing wealth since the 1970s has concentrated
in the hands of the few. Average Americans haven’t gotten happier in
part because average Americans haven’t really gotten wealthier.
• • •
The experts pressing for happiness indicators are reacting to
policymakers’ habit of assessing progress only in terms such as the
Gross National Product. Happiness researchers propose blending their
numbers with other measures of well-being, such as health statistics,
educational attainment, social ties, political voice, and
sustainability. Theirs is a generous and democratic impulse.
Still,
cautions are in order. Politically, this move expands the
generation-long division between tree-hugger and lunch-bucket liberals.
“Post-materialists,” who believe that Americans have wrung out all the
happiness wealth can surrender, argue that we should work on other
sources of happiness, such as personal relationships and experiencing
nature. Materialists, who believe that too many Americans are stuck way
below some wealth-and-happiness optimum, argue that we should keep
pushing for more and better-paid jobs. It’s sort of Seattle Democrats
versus Youngstown Democrats.
More broadly we must ask if
happiness is really the bottom line. Should we discount tragedies
because, research shows, victims typically recover their happiness?
Should happiness data decide policy—where economists are involved,
policy is rarely far away—and could a drug like Brave New World’s soma or an app that stimulates the brain’s pleasure centers be the ultimate policy tool?
The happily contrarian economist Deirdre McCloskey recently unleashed a cannonade on happiness research in The New Republic.
She points out that the happiness industry brings us back to Benthamite
aspirations to assess utility as if by the tailor’s yardstick. She
dismisses the measurement technology and, more fundamentally, the
emphasis on happiness over material conditions. That concern emerges,
she sneers, from the snooty literati’s contempt, born of romantic
pastoralism, for the material needs of average folks. She asks what
gives us most meaning in life and—sounding pretty Seattle-ish
herself—suggests it is more often found in painful striving than in
achievement.
Whatever the philosophical issues around happiness
(oh, the philosophy professors have also joined the pursuit) asking
people questions about their feelings of well-being is a useful
diagnostic tool for research. We learn, for instance, that increasing
economic inequality since the 1970s widened the class gap in feelings of
happiness and that the job and income losses of the Great Recession
have depressed Americans’ average happiness. But these are rough
measures, and whether they can or should guide national policy remains
an open question.
it really awesome to others
ReplyDeleteHappiness Policy well said
ReplyDeletePolicy never works in real Life......
ReplyDeleteDoes work Dude,its how you live ur standards....
ReplyDelete